Economics Online Tutor
When one person or country has a lower opportunity cost in a specific activity than another person or
country, then it is said to have a comparative advantage in that activity.  A comparative advantage
indicates an area where specialization should occur in order to increase total production.  Then, the
good that is specialized in can be traded for the other good.

Even if one party can do more of everything than the other party, both can still gain from specialization
and trade due to comparative advantage.

The concept of comparative advantage is often confused with the concept of absolute advantage.  
Absolute advantage is when one person or country can do more of a particular activity than the other
party, based on the total amount of production that is possible for that activity.  Absolute advantage
has nothing to do with opportunity costs and has no effect on potential gains that can be made from
specialization and trade.  When determining specialization, only comparative advantage matters.

One type of question that comes up very often on tests relating to opportunity costs, specialization,
and trade involves a hypothetical situation of two countries (or individuals) that can each produce two
goods in ratios that are given by numbers of units of each good that it can produce.  People often ask
me questions about this, so I will try to explain it here.  I will use two different methods for explanation:
a formula and an example.  Those who are more comfortable with learning concepts using a formula
can start with the next section before proceeding to the example.  Those who are uncomfortable with
using formulas can just skip to the example.



Using a formula:

This type of question typically looks like this:

Country A can produce (a) number of units of good 1, or it can produce (b) number of units of good 2;
country B can produce (c) number of units of good 1, or it can produce (d) number of units of good 2.  
Which good should each country specialize in?

The answer, using a formula, involves figuring the opportunity cost of each good for each country.  The
country with the lower opportunity cost for a good should specialize in that good.  The opportunity cost
for each good can be calculated with a formula:

For country A, the opportunity cost of good 1 is (b) / (a).  The opportunity cost of good 2 is (a) / (b).

For country B, the opportunity cost of good 1 is (d) / (c).  The opportunity cost of good 2 is (c) / (d).



Using an example instead of just a formula:

Japan can produce 5 cars or 10 computers in an hour.  The United States can produce 3 cars or 12
computers in an hour.  Which good should each country specialize in?

To get the answer, first determine the opportunity cost of the two goods for each country.  The country
with the lower opportunity cost for a good should specialize in that good, and trade with the other
country for the other good.

For Japan, the opportunity cost if 1 car is 2 computers (you get this number by dividing the number of
computers that Japan can produce (10) by the number of cars that it can produce (5) in the same
amount of time.  Using the same method, the opportunity cost to Japan for computers is 1/2 (5 divided
by 10).

For the United States, you use the same method to calculate the opportunity costs.  For cars, that
would be 4 (12 divided by 3); for computers, that would be 1/4 (3 divided by 12).

This means that for cars, Japan's opportunity cost is 2 while the United States' opportunity cost is 4.  
Since Japan's opportunity cost is lower than the United States' (2<4), then Japan should specialize in
the production of cars.

For computers, Japan's opportunity cost is 1/2 while the United States' opportunity cost is 1/4.  Since
the United States' opportunity cost is lower than Japan's (1/4<1/2), then the United States should
specialize in the production of computers.

Then, with specialization, Japan can trade cars to the United States for computers, and both countries
will have more than if they both produced both products and consumed only what they produced
themselves.


To illustrate how specialization can increase total production, start with the above example.  Assume
that without trade, each country will spend an equal amount of time on the production of each good.  
That means that in the same period of time, Japan can produce 5 cars and 10 computers, while the
United States can produce 3 cars and 12 computers.  Together, the two countries produce 8 cars and
22 computers.  But with specialization, Japan will produce 10 cars and zero computers, while the United
States produces zero cars and 24 computers.  Together, with specialization, they end up producing 10
cars and 24 computers.  This is an increase of two cars and two computers due to each country
specializing in the good that it is most efficient at.


You might ask: if they trade, what would be a fair price?  The opportunity costs represent the cost of
each good for each country if they do not trade.  In order to gain from trade, the trade ratio (relative
price) should be somewhere between the opportunity costs for each country.  Otherwise, one country
will not gain from the trade, and the trade will not occur.  Since in the above example, the opportunity
cost per computer for a car is 2 in Japan while it is 4 in the United States, any price between 2 cars per
computer and 4 cars per computer will benefit both countries.


In this example, you might also be asked which country has an absolute advantage in each good.  Since
Japan can produce 5 cars in an hour while the United States can only produce 3 cars in an hour, Japan
has an absolute advantage in cars (5>3).  Since the United States can produce 12 computers in an hour
while Japan can only produce 10 computers in an hour, the United States has an absolute advantage in
computers (12>10).  The absolute advantage was not part of the specialization and trade calculations
because it is irrelevant.  It would be entirely possible for one country to have an absolute advantage in
both goods and still gain from trade, due to different opportunity costs.

It would not be possible for one country to have a comparative advantage in both goods, since
comparative advantage is determined by the relative costs of the two goods.  [If good A costs more in
terms of good B, then it follows that good B could not cost more in terms of good A].
Specialization
& Trade
This page is a continuation of the discussion of opportunity costs.



When individuals or countries specialize in the things that they are good
at, meaning that they are most efficient at or that have the lowest
opportunity costs, then they can trade with others and end up with more
than they could have if they tried to do everything themselves.

Specialization and trade are based on the concept of comparative
advantage.
This page, along with additional commentary, was posted on the "Economics
Online Tutor" Facebook page's timeline on August 6, 2012.
Do you find the information on this page helpful?

The left column of the
home page lists all of the economics topics
covered in this website. Now, you can receive a FREE ebook
version of the information in this site under the title

Basic Economics for Students and Non-Students Alike
By Jerry Wyant

Or if you prefer, you may purchase a paperback version from
Amazon, Barnes & Noble, Sony, Apple, and other distributors.

This makes a great handbook and reference. Students: please
help to make sure your classmates and teachers are aware of this
resource!

Click here to order a FREE ebook from smashwords.com

Click here to purchase a paperback version from amazon.com